The Coming China Crisis
Rapid private-debt growth threw Japan into crisis in 1991 and did the same
to the United States and Europe in 2008. China may be next.
On the morning of September 8, 2016, the
Wenzhou Credit Trust, one of the many trust companies in China, went into
default. The firm discontinued all new lending and suspended redemption and
interest payments on its trust certificates, the equivalent of deposits made by
its customers.
At the time, the failure didn’t seem all that unusual. A handful of trust
companies—“shadow lenders” that make loans, often the riskiest ones, outside of
China’s conventional banks—had done the same in recent years. But within a week,
another trust company went into default, and the following week, so did seven
more. Angry trust-certificate holders protested in Wenzhou and Chongqing but
were quelled by police. Those protests hardly seemed noteworthy at first—for
years, there had been hundreds of protests and disturbances across China—but it
turned out they presaged something new.
Within a month, more than 50 trust companies defaulted. The protests
escalated and spread throughout the country. In the panic, new real-estate
lending plummeted, putting more downward pressure on real-estate prices and
hurting local economies. The Shanghai and Shenzhen stock markets plunged. The
prices of iron, steel, coal, copper, aluminum, and other commodities—including
oil—accelerated their downward spiral.
The government of China, which in recent years had tolerated these
failures as part of its attempt to introduce more risk into the system,
dramatically reversed course and intervened, injecting funds into these lenders
and assuring customers that it would stand behind these institutions. This
calmed equity markets, but commodity prices continued to sag and the renminbi
fell, bringing the specter of devaluation.
By winter, the impact had shattered markets and companies throughout Asia
and Australia, and markets were in retreat in Europe and the United
States.
The Great Panic of China was in full swing.
The future, of course, doesn’t have to unfold this
way. China, the world’s second-largest economy, could still act to prevent much
of the above from happening.
But what cannot be changed is this: China, fueled by runaway lending, has
produced far more housing, steel, iron, and a host of other goods than it knows
what to do with, amassing unprecedented levels of overcapacity and, by my
estimate, making a staggering $2-$3 trillion in problem loans in the process.
And since GDP growth is more a measure of capacity being created than capacity
actually needed, even China’s high rate of GDP growth, fueled almost entirely by
continued ultra-high levels of lending growth, compounds rather than solves
China’s fundamental overcapacity problem.
Which means that the global economic boost from China, the world’s only major
growth engine since the crash of 2008 in the West, is rapidly diminishing and
will soon largely end. The only question is how.
China’s bad-debt problem is unprecedented in scale, but not in nature. In the
United States in 2007 and 2008, we saw our own economy crumble under the weight
of bad debt. And the system didn’t know what hit it: On the eve of our own
collapse, even though more than $1 trillion of bad mortgages had already been
made and major financial fallout was inevitable, banks’ loan-loss provisions—the
amount they set aside to cover bad loans—were near an all-time low, while
consumer net worth and the stock market were at all-time highs.
Neither of the two dominant economic theories of our time forecast the coming
storm. The doves—those more in favor of lower interest rates and government
stimulus—were sanguine, unconcerned by rapid loan growth. The hawks—those more
focused on curbing the money-supply expansion through higher interest rates—were
sounding dire warnings of inflation. Both were wrong, but neither has since
changed its theory.
Our 2007-08 meltdown was entirely foreseeable, despite claims to the
contrary. It was not a “black swan” event. Examining the historical record leads
to the conclusion that major financial crises can be anticipated so long as
you’re on the lookout for the red flag of rapidly rising levels of private debt.
If we are to avoid repeating history, we would do well to observe the Chinese
predicament, understand its implications for the global economy, and apply
lessons to our own economy.
Our Private-Debt Problem
The ongoing debate in Washington over government debt misses the point. In
the years leading up to the U.S. crisis, the remarkable fact was not an increase
in the level of federal debt, but the explosion in the size of
private debt relative to GDP, which rocketed from 120 percent of GDP in
1997 to 165 percent in 2007. By contrast, federal debt barely changed, declining
from 63 percent of GDP to 62 percent during that same period. Private debt is
the sum of consumer debt, including mortgages and business debt. In my view, a
healthy private-debt ratio would be no more than 125 to 150 percent of
GDP.
While many observers missed the signs, some saw that private debt was somehow
key to the American crisis, since the rapid increase in home mortgages was
widely discussed as a culprit. And a closer look at the historical data shows
that this relationship between private data and financial busts appears to be
universal: When we examine financial crises in other countries, we see that—even
when these crises were attributed to other causes—private debt was the
fundamental factor. Private debt can be good when overall levels in a country
are low or moderate, and when, for example, it is used to finance projects whose
income can repay that debt. The problems come when private-debt growth is too
rapid or reaches levels that are too high.
That certainly was the case in Japan in the years before its 1991 financial
crisis:
The chart shows a familiar picture. In the years before the crisis, Japan saw
a major spike in private debt. And that’s the same picture we see in crisis
after crisis.
As I’ve previously written, there is a formula to predicting these crises. A
financial meltdown is probably on the horizon if the ratio of private debt to
GDP rises by roughly 17 percent or more over the course of five years and
exceeds 150 percent. That rise in private debt will likely fuel runaway growth
before the crash (think the 1920s, or Japan’s boom in the 1980s). But those
gains will be evanescent. Driven by private-debt growth, they’ll eventually give
way to a financial crisis.
In past crises—1929, Japan in 1991, the United States in 2008—high government
debt was not the culprit, since in each case the ratio of government
debt to GDP was generally flat or declining. Nor did they correlate with any of
the long list of other widely cited causes, including current account deficits
and interest rates. (Rapidly rising government debt generally becomes an issue
after a crisis, as tax revenue plummets and deficits rise, government
“safety net” programs get higher use, and governments counteract declining
private spending with higher government spending.)
Why does runaway growth in private debt lead to financial crisis? First,
because it means that far too much of something has been built or
produced. It was primarily housing in the United States in 2008; in Japan in
1991, it was primarily commercial real estate. And second, because it means far
too many bad loans have been made in the process. By 2007, for example, the U.S.
banking system had roughly $1.5 trillion in total capital, but an estimated $2.5
trillion in problem loans.
If too much capacity and too many bad loans are the problems, the solutions
are time and capital: time for organic growth to absorb the excess capacity, and
capital to repair banks and borrowers. Monetary and fiscal policies might soften
the blow, but since they do not address those two fundamental issues, they
cannot solve the underlying problem.
The Potential for Crisis in China
The problem for China in 2015 is that it looks a lot like the United States
in 2008 or Japan in 1991.
The growth in the ratio of private debt to GDP over the last five years is an
astonishing 60 percent, and that ratio now exceeds 200 percent. China’s runaway
debt growth has primarily been in business loans, and now its total business
loans are greater than in the United States, even though, based on exchange
rate, U.S. GDP is 82 percent larger than China’s. (For China, we use the term
“private debt” for the sum of business and consumer debt, though some analysts
refer to it as “non-government debt.”)
Quite simply, China has produced and built far too much capacity, through
overinvestment in steel and cement firms and in accelerated housing development.
In the process, it has amassed the largest buildup of bad debt in history.
The cause of the accelerated rise in private debt starting in 2008 was the
collapse of the export market that had fueled China’s growth to that point. From
1999 to 2006, China’s exports-to-GDP ratio had exploded by 95 percent. China’s
net exports, as measured in dollars, were the highest in recorded
history. But they were growing on the shaky foundation of the debt-fueled
expansion of the West that led to the crash of 2008. When that demand
evaporated, China’s exports evaporated too. Addicted to its rapid expansion,
China built a lot of real estate and produced lots of goods—both unjustified by
actual demand—to fill the export hole, all financed by an unprecedented rise in
private debt that is almost certain never to be fully repaid.
As a result, China is now sitting on top of the greatest accumulation of bad
debt and overcapacity in history. According to the Survey and Research Center
for China Household Finance, more than one in five homes in China’s urban areas
is vacant, with 49 million sold but vacant units, and 3.5 million homes that
remain unsold. Behind those vacant and unsold units is private debt, both loans
to developers and mortgage debt. Housing values in China increased on the same
perilous trajectory as in the United States before 2008 and Japan before
1991—and they have now started a similar decline. Meanwhile, real estate was 6
percent of U.S. GDP at the peak in 2005; today, it is as much as 20 percent of
China’s GDP.
There are other red flags. China produced 8 percent of the world’s furnace
iron in 1980; it now produces 61 percent, even though the rest of the world
still continues to produce every bit as much as it has in the past. As China’s
iron production accelerated in the period from 2002 to 2011, iron prices
increased twelvefold in response to debt-fueled demand. (Increases in debt
cause increases in prices.) But now that iron capacity has piled up
beyond need, prices have tumbled by over 50 percent, and the excess capacity is
so great that even the demand generated by rapid credit growth can no longer
prop prices up. Also, China used more cement in the period from 2011 to 2013
(6.6 gigatons) than the United States did in the entire twentieth
century (4.5 gigatons).
These are but a few of many examples. Researchers at a Chinese state planning
agency said recently that China has “wasted” $6.8 trillion in investment.
Overcapacity is so significant in many sectors that it will take years for it to
be absorbed by organic demand. Ironically, this problem is compounded by China’s
own continued high growth rates, since high GDP growth is a measure of the
creation of additional capacity even if that capacity is not needed.
Good and sound loans, by definition, result in commensurate GDP growth. So
when private-loan growth outstrips GDP growth, much of that excess—from
one-quarter to one-half, based on evidence from other crises—will be problem
loans. Based on this formula, China today is likely to have an estimated $1.75
trillion to $3.5 trillion in problem loans—a figure well in excess of the $1.5
trillion of total capital in China’s banking system.
Of course, China’s banks and shadow lenders are not reporting bad loans close
to this amount. But neither did U.S. banks: On the eve of the U.S. crisis, banks
were making loan-loss provisions at very low levels. Lending booms create the
false appearance of prosperity, and fraud and corruption can make the picture
even prettier.
Some dismiss these warning signs, noting that many economic prophets wrongly
made the same dire predictions for China during the late 1990s. But there’s a
big difference: In 1999, China’s overall level of private debt was 111 percent
of GDP; today, it’s almost double that, at 211 percent. In 1999, it had plenty
of room to power growth through continued private-debt expansion, and the debt
boom in the West fueled unprecedented export demand. The opposite is true
today.
China’s Future—and the World’s
China’s slowdown is already underway. Nominal GDP growth has already slowed
from over 15 percent in 2011 to around 7 percent in the last year—and some
analysts believe it’s actually closer to 4 percent. The decline will continue to
play out, perhaps dramatically, over the next three to four years. How well or
badly it plays out, however, depends on the approach the government takes to
simultaneously managing both the short-term problem (slowing growth) and the
longer-term problem (the overhang of private debt).
The trouble for China is that these two challenges summon conflicting
responses. GDP growth in any economy is largely dependent on private-credit
growth, yet the Chinese private sector is massively overleveraged. Ramping up
credit might reverse the slowdown but will further increase bad debt and
compound the ultimate problem; reining in debt, on the other hand, would help
the debt problem but slow down growth.
True, China’s economy is largely a closed system that can make—and
suspend—its own rules, which means China’s leaders can prop up their lending
system for a time. (Even Japan was able to prop up its banks for several years
after its stock market collapse.) What they can likely no longer do, however, is
effectively prop up real estate and commodity prices. Over time, because the
decline in real estate and commodity prices is evidence of China’s overcapacity
and those assets are collateral for so much debt, it will be China’s Achilles’
heel.
Issue #36, Spring 2015
The Coming China Crisis
Rapid private-debt growth threw Japan into crisis in 1991 and did the same to the United States and Europe in 2008. China may be next.
The fundamental problem is that China has misused debt to grow far faster
than income growth prudently allowed. While on the surface the choices look bad,
China—with its vast assets and low central government debt—in fact has the tools
to navigate this crisis yet. China’s impulse is to return to practices that have
succeeded in the past, so it’s difficult to imagine it abandoning the three
pillars of its past growth strategy: exports, business credit growth, and
infrastructure spending. But there is now a diminishing return from each:
exports are constrained by low global demand; businesses are already
overleveraged; and China has already built too many roads to nowhere.
Since these will not suffice, China will likely consider other growth
channels: increasing consumer credit growth; ramping up other categories of
government spending such as military spending; encouraging continued migration
of rural populations to the cities; and perhaps even renewed devaluation. But
these options, if employed, will still collectively fall short.
China’s consumers reportedly do have low leverage, but household debt is
already growing much more rapidly than is prudent, and is ultimately limited by
household income. And consumer debt in China may be higher than indicated due to
high levels of unreported, informal consumer lending. Further, China’s consumers
have put a major portion of their savings in real estate—many own several
apartments—so the ongoing decline in housing values will discourage consumers
from taking on significant new debt.
Increased government spending could help pick up the slack, especially if it
is focused on areas where there is not already too much capacity, such as
military spending. But even here, the scope and pace of additional spending are
inherently limited by operational realities. China hopes to bring hundreds of
millions more rural Chinese citizens to the cities, to increase both wages and
housing demand. But these plans crucially depend on job growth to support these
migrants, and job creation has been a leading casualty of slowing exports.
Finally, devaluation works best when matched with high global demand, risks
driving out badly needed foreign capital, and, in any event, would likely be
matched by competitive devaluations from other nations.
Both “rebalancing” and “reform” are cited as important parts of the solution.
Rebalancing is needed—China’s growth has been far too dependent on investment by
its businesses as compared to consumption by its households. But rebalancing is
hard work that will take years, not quickly enough to reverse China’s
decelerating growth. Reform of business practices is needed as well, but that
too will be very difficult, and likely won’t happen fast enough.
Some believe that through continued high productivity gains, China can
sustain high growth without worsening its private-debt picture. But in recent
years private-debt growth has almost equaled China’s increased productivity,
calling into question the sustainability of those increases absent continued
high private-debt growth.
Panic and the Path of Contagion
Reckoning with Private Debt
Because there are few good choices to adequately boost growth, the continued
decline in commodity prices and real estate will make the problem loans in
China’s banks worse, as a massive amount of the country’s private debt is
secured by commodities and real estate. Based on its recent behavior, the
Chinese government will likely address deteriorating bank loan quality with an
overt and broad guarantee to consumers for deposits and possibly also wealth and
trust certificates. It will also quietly fortify these lenders with capital. If
China pursues these policy choices, it will indeed avoid an immediate financial
crisis. But it ultimately cannot reverse the trend of decelerating growth over
the next three to four years—perhaps to a level approaching zero—and China will
be left facing a “lost” generation of very low growth similar to the last 20
years in Japan.
The question facing the rest of the world is whether there will be a crisis
in other countries because of China’s troubles. What will the path of financial
contagion be?
Financial contagion is not some mysterious force that overtakes the healthy
and unsuspecting. Any impact on non-Chinese companies and countries will come
from: 1) overlending to troubled Chinese banks and businesses; 2) an
overconcentration of exports to China; 3) a dependence on high commodity prices;
and 4) a currency devaluation necessitated in an export-oriented country because
of a devaluation by China.
Most countries in the Asia-Pacific region have significant export
concentrations to China and will be adversely affected by China’s slowdown, as
will many countries in Africa and South America. Europe has exposure too,
especially in the area of high-end automobiles and luxury goods. The United
States has more limited exposure, but some sectors such as high-tech and
construction have significant sales in China.
Although there are allegedly low levels of foreign debt in China, these
levels may be underreported; banks that have lent to companies or banks in China
face real risk as growth decelerates. Hong Kong, Singapore, and the UK are among
those with the highest lending exposure to China. Countries dependent on high
oil and other commodities prices are also at risk. If China devalues its
currency, many of its export-oriented Asian neighbors would be forced to follow
suit—and in fact may act to devalue ahead of China—bringing the specter of a
banking crisis to these countries.
Reckoning with Private Debt
In the 1980s and early ’90s, my formative business years, the media regularly
trumpeted the news that Japan was ascendant and would eclipse the United States
as the world’s business leader. When Japanese firms purchased iconic properties
such as Rockefeller Center in New York and Pebble Beach golf resort in
California, it was confirmation of that trend. In the 1980s, Japan reached 18
percent of world GDP. Today its share of GDP has fallen to 7 percent. We now
know that its seeming path to dominance was paved with runaway private debt.
While China’s trajectory might not be the same as Japan’s, there are profound
similarities. China has had years of runaway private-debt growth, and its GDP
growth is now decelerating. There is no doubt that China, with a population over
1.3 billion, will be an increasingly important player in the world, economically
and otherwise. But there has been a tendency to overestimate what China can
achieve economically over the near term. America’s economy is almost twice the
size of China’s, and our relative influence will continue to reflect that
difference.
Indeed, we should take a more balanced view of China. With its growth, China
has had a significantly higher profile in a variety of policy areas. It has been
more assertive in military matters. It has expressed a desire to have the
renminbi take its place as one of the world’s reserve currencies—in essence
competing with the U.S. dollar for a bigger role in the world’s economy. U.S.
policy-makers have struggled with how to respond to this assertiveness. Much of
it should be unsurprising, given China’s rise to its current position as the
world’s second-largest economy. But even with its successes, China now presides
over enormous and in some respects unprecedented internal problems, and we
should understand the limitations they impose on what the country can achieve in
the near term and resist making policy blunders by overestimating its relative
strength.
So what should China do? My recommended course is for the country to directly
address not slowing growth, which is only a symptom, but the real problems:
overcapacity and excessive private debt. In this scenario, China would prudently
slow both lending and growth, allowing demand to begin to catch up with
overcapacity. What’s more, China would also preemptively recapitalize its
lenders.
However, my recommendation goes well beyond China’s past cosmetic bank
cleanups. It needs to take the further step of requiring lenders to broadly,
quickly, and decisively restructure debt with overburdened corporate
borrowers—to provide, in other words, real debt relief and restructuring that
allows those corporations to resume productive investment, not simply accounting
sleight of hand. Otherwise, high debt will linger for years as a long-term drag
on China’s economic prospects.
Large-scale corporate debt relief would be complex and difficult. But the
lesson from Japan’s experience, where the private-debt-to-GDP ratio reached a
staggering 221 percent, and timely and meaningful debt restructuring was not
adopted, is that it’s necessary. A generation later, Japan’s private-debt-to-GDP
ratio is still a stifling 170 percent and remains the neglected central issue in
Japan’s lackluster growth.
China may never undertake such systemic private-debt restructuring, but it is
the surest path to revitalizing its beleaguered business sector, remedying
overcapacity issues, stabilizing prices, and restoring reasonable growth. By
alleviating rather than simply disguising China’s high private-debt-to-GDP
problem, it would leave corporations in a much better position to lead renewed
(and, hopefully this time, more measured) growth after the slowdown.
Lessons for America
Runaway private debt brought America to its economic knees in 2008. It did
the same to Japan in 1991. And it is in the process of doing the same to China.
Yet the schools of economic thought that dominate thinking and policy-making in
Washington pay scant attention to private debt. And so our economists and
politicians will continue to err in forecasting crises, and will also make
inadequate repairs after the fact. Just as runaway private debt causes crisis,
the overhang of private debt after the crisis constrains growth. Private debt
has been underemphasized by economists in some measure because of the view that
for every borrower there is a lender, and thus private debt “nets” to zero. This
view neglects consideration of the distribution of debt: Lenders tend to be
institutions, and borrowers tend to be those middle- and lower-income households
most needed to sustain economic growth. Private debt has also been
underemphasized because public debt seems more our public responsibility, and
private debt seems more off-limits—the domain of the private sector and “the
invisible hand.”
Seven years after our own crisis, private debt in the United States stands at
143 percent of GDP—lower than its apex of 167 percent in 2008, but still high.
The high level of private debt in the United States represents a drag on
economic growth, most starkly evident in the almost nine million of the nation’s
53 million mortgages that remain underwater. In fact, private-debt levels across
the globe remain sky-high—not that anybody’s paying attention. The piling up of
private debt over decades smothers demand and dampens economic growth.
China’s economic challenges offer the United States an opportunity to learn
and recalibrate our economic thinking. Like China, we should now concentrate on
scaling back private debt (which we did not do in the aftermath of the 2008
crisis). We need to act differently this time around if we are to avoid having
our recovery swamped by the next slowdown (from China or anywhere else). Debt
relief in the form of restructuring or partial debt forgiveness should be
seriously considered as an option. What if we were to let lenders write down
underwater mortgages over an extended time frame (30 years)? While less
necessary today, if this had been done in 2008, it would have made an enormous
difference in the trajectory of the recovery.
Our policy-makers should move beyond the fixation with public debt and turn
their attention to the true problem of private debt. They should recognize the
inadequacy of the timeworn tools of monetary and fiscal policy and lead a
discussion of strategies—especially restructuring—to address the key issue of
historically high private-debt levels. Indeed, low private debt, combined with
low capacity (the supply of housing, factories, etc.), was the precondition for
the economic boom we experienced in the post-World War II decades.
China’s downturn will only add to our challenges. The modern world has had
four major economic engines—the United States, China, Europe, and Japan—which
together constitute 60 percent of world GDP. While the United States moves
toward respectable growth, both Europe and Japan—also hobbled with high private
debt—are struggling to show any progress.
But it is China we should be worried about. China is facing a generation of
dramatically slower growth. Its slowdown will cause trouble for its trading
partners and lenders across the globe. And while the economic impact in the
United States will be softer than in any other major country, China is now so
large that we too will feel it.
The question is whether we will also learn from it.
No hay comentarios:
Publicar un comentario